Birth

Birth

Life Expectancy at Birth (in the Human Development Area)

In this context, Life Expectancy at Birth means: number of years a newborn infant could expect to live if prevailing patterns of age-specific mortality rates at the time of birth were to stay the same throughout the infant’s life.

Probability at Birth of Not Surviving to a Specified Age (in the Human Development Area)

In this context, Probability at Birth of Not Surviving to a Specified Age means: calculated as 100 minus the probability (expressed as a percentage) of surviving to a specified age for a given cohort. See Probability at birth of surviving to a specified age.

Probability at Birth of Surviving to a Specified Age (in the Human Development Area)

In this context, Probability at Birth of Surviving to a Specified Age means: the probability of a newborn infant surviving to a specified age if subject to prevailing patterns of age-specific mortality rates, expressed as a percentage.

Low Birth Rates

Not long ago a vocal concern was about high fertility in the world and a rapidly growing population. Remember the currently quiet zero population growth (ZPG) movement? The tide has turned since the worry now is about too few births and a falling population.

The reason for this shift in attitude is that over 80 countries have fewer births than required to replace the number of individuals who die each year. They need a large flow of immigrants each year just to prevent their populations from peaking and then declining. These low birth countries contain over 40% of the world’s population, including every country in Western Europe, China, Japan, Russia, Poland, and Canada, to name just a few. Birth rates in many other countries, including the United States, Mexico, and Iran, are only a little above the level necessary to replace the number of deaths.

Scholars measure the level of fertility by the total fertility rate (TFR), which equals the average number of children born to women over their lifetimes. Countries with TFRs below the replacement level of about 2.1 fall into the low fertility camp. Essentially no countries were in this camp in 1970, but in each succeeding decade many additional countries fell below replacement levels. Moreover, and this is important, in not a single country has the TFR ever risen above replacement once it fell below.

As late as the beginning of this century, demographers and others were predicting a rapid growth in world population to over 11 billion by the year 2050. The rapid emergence of low fertility in so many countries has already made these forecasts obsolete. Populations forecasts now assume much lower future fertility levels, but even the present consensus that world population will be about 9 1/2 billion by mid-century may be too high as fertility continues to fall rapidly in poorer countries.

There is growing discussion in many low fertility countries about the negative consequences of having fewer young persons, and the prospects, already a reality in Germany, Japan, Russia, and a few other countries with low immigration levels, of declining populations. In richer countries, retirement incomes and medical care of the elderly are largely financed by taxes on the younger working population. Low birth rates eventually lead to fewer men and women of working ages, and hence a smaller tax base to finance social security payments, unless the fewer children born have sufficiently greater amounts invested in their education and other human capital.

Although potential difficulties in financing social security benefits are receiving the most attention, other negative effects of low birth rates may be of equal or greater importance. Low fertility reduces the rate of scientific and other innovations since innovations mainly come from younger individuals. Younger individuals are also generally more adaptable, which is why new industries, like high tech startups, generally attract younger workers who are not yet committed to older and declining industries.

The great majority of countries have had growing populations during the past 250 years as world population grew at unprecedented rates. Yet ever since Malthus wrote his great work on the harmful effects of population growth on incomes, group after group have opposed high fertility and growing populations as bad for the world’s food supply, standard of living, and environment, including local and global pollution.

However, these possible negative effects of larger populations have to be weighed against the sizable benefits from more people. These benefits include a larger number of young persons who, as mentioned earlier, are more likely to innovate, such as coming up with more efficient ways to grow food, and pay for the benefits to retired men and women. A bigger population also increases the demand for new drugs, software, social networking, and other innovations that have increasing returns to the scale of demand.

To be sure, if higher birth rates lead to lesser education and other human capital investments in each child, they may result in lower, not higher, per capita incomes. Malthus fear of lower per capita incomes explains his strong opposition to high birth rates. However, the rapid growth in world population during past 250 years has been accompanied by unprecedented high per capita incomes all over the world. Whatever the Malthusian negative effects of greater population, they have been dominated by factors that raised per capita incomes, including the benefits of increasing returns and other advantages from having a larger population.

China is seriously considering either greatly modifying or completely abandoning its “one child” policy because of its effects on the number of young persons, and population decline. France a while back instituted a generous and expensive system of financial support to families that have 2 or more births. Germany, Japan, South Korea, Russia, and other countries are discussing and sometimes implementing similar child support programs.

Whether a subsidy is justified depends on whether the benefits from more births and a larger population, including the benefits to the families having children, exceed the cost of encouraging births, such as the budgetary costs to governments of a child support program, potentially greater environmental damage, and the like. Even if, as I firmly believe, that on the whole greater population in the modern world has more benefits than costs, one has to recognize that programs to stimulate births are expensive, aside from simply ending birth suppression policies, as in China’s one child regulatory policy,

For example, to cut the gap in half between Germany’s actual TFR of about 1.4 and a replacement level of fertility of 2.1 requires a 25% increase in the number of births. Yet such a large increase in fertility has not been achieved by any past fertility subsidy programs, even expensive ones, presumably because children are so costly to raise in the money, time, and energy of parents. A more modest 10-15 percent growth in fertility might be achievable with generous and expensive programs, as in France. Perhaps a full benefit cost analysis would show that such a program is warranted, but the jury on this is still out.

Author: Becker, defunct


Posted

in

,

by

Comments

13 responses to “Birth”

  1. international

    Johnatan

    While fertility is an important part of keeping a powerful, mobile and advancing workforce part of the economy, there simply may not be enough room for that model anymore.

    Malthus wrote his classic in the 19th century; well before modern innovations dashed his predictions for a crushing carrying capacity on earth: we haven’t begun making Soylent Green either. Although technological innovation may push the carrying capacity of earth some more, its clear that current rates of population growth may be unsustainable within two or three generations.

    The idea espoused rings true to me; among the millions born every year, surely one Feynman, one Einstein, one George Bernard Shaw must be born among them. But the more frightening prospect isn’t that great people will no longer be born, but that they are already born and are starving away. In finance jargon, instead of capital widening, perhaps we too should deepen our capital.

  2. international

    Johnatan

    While fertility is an important part of keeping a powerful, mobile and advancing workforce part of the economy, there simply may not be enough room for that model anymore.

    Malthus wrote his classic in the 19th century; well before modern innovations dashed his predictions for a crushing carrying capacity on earth: we haven’t begun making Soylent Green either. Although technological innovation may push the carrying capacity of earth some more, its clear that current rates of population growth may be unsustainable within two or three generations.

    The idea espoused rings true to me; among the millions born every year, surely one Feynman, one Einstein, one George Bernard Shaw must be born among them. But the more frightening prospect isn’t that great people will no longer be born, but that they are already born and are starving away. In finance jargon, instead of capital widening, perhaps we too should deepen our capital.

  3. international

    Thomas Andres

    I can’t believe there are those who still think this way and are blinded to the fact the world is already over populated and getting worse in spite of all the amazing new technology. Only an economist using past models can support this blog. Anyone who steps out in the real world can see what unsustainable destruction we are causing to the environment and massive extinctions, not to mention the spread of a lower standard of living among the vast majority of humans. More humans on the planet will only make matters worse. Why is that so difficult to see?

  4. international

    Thomas Andres

    I can’t believe there are those who still think this way and are blinded to the fact the world is already over populated and getting worse in spite of all the amazing new technology. Only an economist using past models can support this blog. Anyone who steps out in the real world can see what unsustainable destruction we are causing to the environment and massive extinctions, not to mention the spread of a lower standard of living among the vast majority of humans. More humans on the planet will only make matters worse. Why is that so difficult to see?

  5. international

    Gertrud

    How about reforming social security to make part of your pension tied to the incomes of all your CHILDREN? People without children generally have an easy time to save up enough for retirement anyway, so such a change should not cause too much distress or inequality. And it would encourage parents not just to have more children but also raise them in such a manner as to become productive, tax-paying citizens.

  6. international

    Gertrud

    How about reforming social security to make part of your pension tied to the incomes of all your CHILDREN? People without children generally have an easy time to save up enough for retirement anyway, so such a change should not cause too much distress or inequality. And it would encourage parents not just to have more children but also raise them in such a manner as to become productive, tax-paying citizens.

  7. international

    Chris Bates

    You may have a point, but those that can not bear children are penalized through no fault of their own. Add a work related total disability and you have a statistical corundum, and having child for a meal ticket and there will be adult children spending their money on psychotherapy.

    FYI: Social Security is not a pension, I think of it as a form of savings like whole life insurance, one which requires 10 years to get vested.

  8. international

    Chris Bates

    You may have a point, but those that can not bear children are penalized through no fault of their own. Add a work related total disability and you have a statistical corundum, and having child for a meal ticket and there will be adult children spending their money on psychotherapy.

    FYI: Social Security is not a pension, I think of it as a form of savings like whole life insurance, one which requires 10 years to get vested.

  9. international

    Gertrud

    There is a fundamental problem with externalities here. A potential additional child is extremely likely to (in retrospect) value life. Unless there is expected to be severe crowding or food shortages, there will not much of negative consequences to other future individuals. The producers of children however cannot fully capture the positive externalities – the “utility” that future generations will enjoy. Economic theory clearly tells us that we should get underproduction. To take a concrete example, a family might well have one or two children simply because of the joy of children. But going beyond that may be viewed as too costly. Nevertheless, potential child #3 and child #4, if born, would be willing and able to pay the parents for the privilege of being born. As it is now, future children end up financing the retirement of all old people, with the parents themselves not receiving any additional share.

  10. international

    Gertrud

    There is a fundamental problem with externalities here. A potential additional child is extremely likely to (in retrospect) value life. Unless there is expected to be severe crowding or food shortages, there will not much of negative consequences to other future individuals. The producers of children however cannot fully capture the positive externalities – the “utility” that future generations will enjoy. Economic theory clearly tells us that we should get underproduction. To take a concrete example, a family might well have one or two children simply because of the joy of children. But going beyond that may be viewed as too costly. Nevertheless, potential child #3 and child #4, if born, would be willing and able to pay the parents for the privilege of being born. As it is now, future children end up financing the retirement of all old people, with the parents themselves not receiving any additional share.

  11. international

    Sara

    There is sooo much land on earth. Its resources and our technologies will always be enough to live well. If every day people are born, many others die too. Then there are these natural disasters that play their part and make a balance again. But isnt technology more to blame than humans for over exploitation of resources. Im not for over population, but if I want to be against over population then these are the points that come to my mind.

  12. international

    Terry Bennetty

    Rick Jarow has written on the fundamental perspectives of scarcity and abundance. Putting aside the logistics of allocation for the moment, do you think there is enough for everybody, or don’t you? People who believe in abundance (i.e., optimists) tend to be happier and more successful.

    Beyond the psychology, there is an objective question, and it’s not simply, “Does the world have too many people?” Rather, we must factor in the progression of technology over time. If the United States had today’s population and the technology of 1789, we’d probably have mass starvation/dehydration, decimations by disease, and wars driven by demand for resources. Can the world support 10 billion? Not right now, but very possibly in 50 or 100 years. In 2013 A.D., a large portion of the 7 billion currently alive are not living very well. To some, that’s the same as saying we’re overpopulated. Others might say it proves the haves are too selfish to provide for the have nots. (To the extent that I am a have, it is solely because I’m also a went out and got. I do not see why anyone wishing to be a have cannot simply choose to work and meet that goal, in whatever desired degree, and I reject the communist argument.)

    Does a new child born today represent a net positive or a net negative over a coming lifetime, production minus consumption? According to Mitt Romney we’re already at 47% net negatives. I suspect it’s actually higher. The entire World War II generation is being subsidized out the wazoo with modern health care they did not earn (at least in a strict economic sense), and the baby boomers stand to be even more decidedly takers rather than givers. I have zero reason for optimism that larger numbers of individuals in future generations will pull their own weight than in recent generations. I think it’s just going to get worse, and therefore as an economic endeavor, I’d give 5 to 1 that any new child will be a loser. Jim Kirby is right that immigrants bring with them the positive externality of their formative costs, but even so I think they are mostly economic losers too. The costs of modern life are simply too high for most people to meet. (Immigrants also tend to have more kids, which means more costs to us.)

    So if most people are net negatives, where is the production coming from to feed us right now? Some of it comes from past surplus, some of it comes from current production, and a very disturbing piece of it comes from borrowing against the future. If we were in fact pulling our own weight, we wouldn’t be needing to borrow, would we now? Stated another way, where is all this money we borrow going? It’s going to pay for the consumption of people who have not produced enough to pay for it themselves. The poor demand subsidy; the rich refuse to pay for it. We aren’t ones to let a little impasse like that stop us. We borrow, and everybody’s happy – except future generations, but they aren’t here to gripe, so they can just eat cake and pound sand.

  13. international

    Terry Bennetty

    Rick Jarow has written on the fundamental perspectives of scarcity and abundance. Putting aside the logistics of allocation for the moment, do you think there is enough for everybody, or don’t you? People who believe in abundance (i.e., optimists) tend to be happier and more successful.

    Beyond the psychology, there is an objective question, and it’s not simply, “Does the world have too many people?” Rather, we must factor in the progression of technology over time. If the United States had today’s population and the technology of 1789, we’d probably have mass starvation/dehydration, decimations by disease, and wars driven by demand for resources. Can the world support 10 billion? Not right now, but very possibly in 50 or 100 years. In 2013 A.D., a large portion of the 7 billion currently alive are not living very well. To some, that’s the same as saying we’re overpopulated. Others might say it proves the haves are too selfish to provide for the have nots. (To the extent that I am a have, it is solely because I’m also a went out and got. I do not see why anyone wishing to be a have cannot simply choose to work and meet that goal, in whatever desired degree, and I reject the communist argument.)

    Does a new child born today represent a net positive or a net negative over a coming lifetime, production minus consumption? According to Mitt Romney we’re already at 47% net negatives. I suspect it’s actually higher. The entire World War II generation is being subsidized out the wazoo with modern health care they did not earn (at least in a strict economic sense), and the baby boomers stand to be even more decidedly takers rather than givers. I have zero reason for optimism that larger numbers of individuals in future generations will pull their own weight than in recent generations. I think it’s just going to get worse, and therefore as an economic endeavor, I’d give 5 to 1 that any new child will be a loser. Jim Kirby is right that immigrants bring with them the positive externality of their formative costs, but even so I think they are mostly economic losers too. The costs of modern life are simply too high for most people to meet. (Immigrants also tend to have more kids, which means more costs to us.)

    So if most people are net negatives, where is the production coming from to feed us right now? Some of it comes from past surplus, some of it comes from current production, and a very disturbing piece of it comes from borrowing against the future. If we were in fact pulling our own weight, we wouldn’t be needing to borrow, would we now? Stated another way, where is all this money we borrow going? It’s going to pay for the consumption of people who have not produced enough to pay for it themselves. The poor demand subsidy; the rich refuse to pay for it. We aren’t ones to let a little impasse like that stop us. We borrow, and everybody’s happy – except future generations, but they aren’t here to gripe, so they can just eat cake and pound sand.